Car accidents in the age of robots
<?xml version="1.0" encoding="UTF-8"?><collection xmlns="http://www.loc.gov/MARC21/slim" xmlns:xsi="http://www.w3.org/2001/XMLSchema-instance" xsi:schemaLocation="http://www.loc.gov/MARC21/slim http://www.loc.gov/standards/marcxml/schema/MARC21slim.xsd">
<record>
<leader>00000nab a22000004b 4500</leader>
<controlfield tag="001">MAP20210029882</controlfield>
<controlfield tag="003">MAP</controlfield>
<controlfield tag="005">20211018170358.0</controlfield>
<controlfield tag="008">211018e20210916gbr|| p |0|||b|eng d</controlfield>
<datafield tag="040" ind1=" " ind2=" ">
<subfield code="a">MAP</subfield>
<subfield code="b">spa</subfield>
</datafield>
<datafield tag="084" ind1=" " ind2=" ">
<subfield code="a">911.6</subfield>
</datafield>
<datafield tag="245" ind1="1" ind2="0">
<subfield code="a">Car accidents in the age of robots</subfield>
<subfield code="c">Alessandro De Chiara... [et al.]</subfield>
</datafield>
<datafield tag="300" ind1=" " ind2=" ">
<subfield code="a">14 p.</subfield>
</datafield>
<datafield tag="520" ind1=" " ind2=" ">
<subfield code="a">In this paper, the authors compare liability rules in a world where human-driven and fully-autonomous cars coexist. We develop a model where a manufacturer can invest to improve the safety of autonomous cars. Human drivers may decide to purchase a fully-autonomous car to save precaution costs to avoid road accidents and shift liability to the car manufacturer. As compared to the negligence rule, a strict liability regime on both human drivers and car manufacturers is proved to be a superior policy. In particular, strict liability leads to more efficient R&D investments to enhance the benefits of the technology and favors the adoption of fully-autonomous cars. They also recommend that users of fully-autonomous cars make a technology-dependent payment to a third-party if there is an accident to discipline their activity levels</subfield>
</datafield>
<datafield tag="650" ind1=" " ind2="4">
<subfield code="0">MAPA20080599751</subfield>
<subfield code="a">Accidentes de tráfico</subfield>
</datafield>
<datafield tag="650" ind1=" " ind2="4">
<subfield code="0">MAPA20080603588</subfield>
<subfield code="a">Responsabilidad civil</subfield>
</datafield>
<datafield tag="650" ind1=" " ind2="4">
<subfield code="0">MAPA20150019967</subfield>
<subfield code="a">Vehículos autónomos</subfield>
</datafield>
<datafield tag="650" ind1=" " ind2="4">
<subfield code="0">MAPA20080588618</subfield>
<subfield code="a">Vehículos de motor</subfield>
</datafield>
<datafield tag="650" ind1=" " ind2="4">
<subfield code="0">MAPA20080558352</subfield>
<subfield code="a">Fabricantes</subfield>
</datafield>
<datafield tag="650" ind1=" " ind2="4">
<subfield code="0">MAPA20080605674</subfield>
<subfield code="a">Desarrollo tecnológico</subfield>
</datafield>
<datafield tag="650" ind1=" " ind2="4">
<subfield code="0">MAPA20080603779</subfield>
<subfield code="a">Seguro de automóviles</subfield>
</datafield>
<datafield tag="700" ind1="1" ind2=" ">
<subfield code="0">MAPA20210033810</subfield>
<subfield code="a">Chiara, Alessandro de</subfield>
</datafield>
<datafield tag="773" ind1="0" ind2=" ">
<subfield code="t">International Review of Law and Economics.- Oxford : Elsevier</subfield>
<subfield code="g">nº 68, September 2021</subfield>
</datafield>
</record>
</collection>