Sunk costs and screening: two-part tariffs in life insurance
<?xml version="1.0" encoding="UTF-8"?><collection xmlns="http://www.loc.gov/MARC21/slim" xmlns:xsi="http://www.w3.org/2001/XMLSchema-instance" xsi:schemaLocation="http://www.loc.gov/MARC21/slim http://www.loc.gov/standards/marcxml/schema/MARC21slim.xsd">
<record>
<leader>00000cab a2200000 4500</leader>
<controlfield tag="001">MAP20200028949</controlfield>
<controlfield tag="003">MAP</controlfield>
<controlfield tag="005">20220911202042.0</controlfield>
<controlfield tag="008">200921e20200901usa|||p |0|||b|eng d</controlfield>
<datafield tag="040" ind1=" " ind2=" ">
<subfield code="a">MAP</subfield>
<subfield code="b">spa</subfield>
<subfield code="d">MAP</subfield>
</datafield>
<datafield tag="084" ind1=" " ind2=" ">
<subfield code="a">6</subfield>
</datafield>
<datafield tag="245" ind1="1" ind2="0">
<subfield code="a">Sunk costs and screening: two-part tariffs in life insurance</subfield>
<subfield code="c">James M. Carson..[Et al.]</subfield>
</datafield>
<datafield tag="520" ind1=" " ind2=" ">
<subfield code="a">We develop a model of insurance pricing under heterogeneous lapse rates with asymmetric information about lapse likelihood within the context of an optional two-part tariff as a screening device for future policyholder behavior. We then test for consumer self-selection using policy-level data on life insurance backdating. We exploit randomness in the initial tariff size to separately identify the selection and sunk cost effects of backdating on lapse proclivity. We find that consumers who are less likely to lapse self-select into the two-part tariff pricing structure and we also document consumer behavior consistent with sunk cost fallacy.</subfield>
</datafield>
<datafield tag="650" ind1=" " ind2="4">
<subfield code="0">MAPA20080570590</subfield>
<subfield code="a">Seguro de vida</subfield>
</datafield>
<datafield tag="650" ind1=" " ind2="4">
<subfield code="0">MAPA20080586294</subfield>
<subfield code="a">Mercado de seguros</subfield>
</datafield>
<datafield tag="650" ind1=" " ind2="4">
<subfield code="0">MAPA20080602437</subfield>
<subfield code="a">Matemática del seguro</subfield>
</datafield>
<datafield tag="650" ind1=" " ind2="4">
<subfield code="0">MAPA20080598358</subfield>
<subfield code="a">Productos de seguros</subfield>
</datafield>
<datafield tag="650" ind1=" " ind2="4">
<subfield code="0">MAPA20080624019</subfield>
<subfield code="a">Comportamiento del consumidor</subfield>
</datafield>
<datafield tag="650" ind1=" " ind2="4">
<subfield code="0">MAPA20080545062</subfield>
<subfield code="a">Precios</subfield>
</datafield>
<datafield tag="700" ind1=" " ind2=" ">
<subfield code="0">MAPA20080662882</subfield>
<subfield code="a">Carson, James M.</subfield>
</datafield>
<datafield tag="773" ind1="0" ind2=" ">
<subfield code="w">MAP20077000727</subfield>
<subfield code="t">The Journal of risk and insurance</subfield>
<subfield code="d">Nueva York : The American Risk and Insurance Association, 1964-</subfield>
<subfield code="x">0022-4367</subfield>
<subfield code="g">01/09/2020 Volumen 87 Número 3 - septiembre 2020 , p. 689-718</subfield>
</datafield>
</record>
</collection>