Multi Cumulative Prospect Theory and the Demand for Cliquet-Style Guarantees
<?xml version="1.0" encoding="UTF-8"?><collection xmlns="http://www.loc.gov/MARC21/slim" xmlns:xsi="http://www.w3.org/2001/XMLSchema-instance" xsi:schemaLocation="http://www.loc.gov/MARC21/slim http://www.loc.gov/standards/marcxml/schema/MARC21slim.xsd">
<record>
<leader>00000cab a2200000 4500</leader>
<controlfield tag="001">MAP20190000697</controlfield>
<controlfield tag="003">MAP</controlfield>
<controlfield tag="005">20190111142711.0</controlfield>
<controlfield tag="008">190108e20181203esp|||p |0|||b|spa d</controlfield>
<datafield tag="040" ind1=" " ind2=" ">
<subfield code="a">MAP</subfield>
<subfield code="b">spa</subfield>
<subfield code="d">MAP</subfield>
</datafield>
<datafield tag="084" ind1=" " ind2=" ">
<subfield code="a">921.9</subfield>
</datafield>
<datafield tag="100" ind1=" " ind2=" ">
<subfield code="0">MAPA20190000277</subfield>
<subfield code="a">Rub, Jochen</subfield>
</datafield>
<datafield tag="245" ind1="1" ind2="0">
<subfield code="a">Multi Cumulative Prospect Theory and the Demand for Cliquet-Style Guarantees</subfield>
<subfield code="c">Jochen Rub, Stefan Schelling</subfield>
</datafield>
<datafield tag="520" ind1=" " ind2=" ">
<subfield code="a">Expected Utility Theory (EUT) and Cumulative Prospect Theory (CPT) face problems explaining preferences of long-term investors. Previous research motivates that the subjective utility of a long-term investment also depends on interim value changes. Therefore, we propose an approach that we call Multi Cumulative Prospect Theory. It is based on CPT and considers annual changes in the contract values. As a first application, we can show that in contrast to EUT and CPT, this approach is able to explain the demand for guaranteed products with lock-in features, which in this framework generate a higher subjective utility than products without or with simpler guarantees</subfield>
</datafield>
<datafield tag="650" ind1=" " ind2="4">
<subfield code="0">MAPA20080597641</subfield>
<subfield code="a">Mercados financieros</subfield>
</datafield>
<datafield tag="650" ind1=" " ind2="4">
<subfield code="0">MAPA20080558970</subfield>
<subfield code="a">Inversiones</subfield>
</datafield>
<datafield tag="650" ind1=" " ind2="4">
<subfield code="0">MAPA20080603182</subfield>
<subfield code="a">Productos financieros</subfield>
</datafield>
<datafield tag="650" ind1=" " ind2="4">
<subfield code="0">MAPA20080592059</subfield>
<subfield code="a">Modelos predictivos</subfield>
</datafield>
<datafield tag="650" ind1=" " ind2="4">
<subfield code="0">MAPA20080592011</subfield>
<subfield code="a">Modelos actuariales</subfield>
</datafield>
<datafield tag="650" ind1=" " ind2="4">
<subfield code="0">MAPA20080601492</subfield>
<subfield code="a">Estudios comparativos</subfield>
</datafield>
<datafield tag="650" ind1=" " ind2="4">
<subfield code="0">MAPA20080606718</subfield>
<subfield code="a">Información financiera</subfield>
</datafield>
<datafield tag="700" ind1="1" ind2=" ">
<subfield code="0">MAPA20190000284</subfield>
<subfield code="a">Schelling, Stefan</subfield>
</datafield>
<datafield tag="773" ind1="0" ind2=" ">
<subfield code="w">MAP20077000727</subfield>
<subfield code="t">The Journal of risk and insurance</subfield>
<subfield code="d">Nueva York : The American Risk and Insurance Association, 1964-</subfield>
<subfield code="x">0022-4367</subfield>
<subfield code="g">03/12/2018 Volumen 85 Número 4 - diciembre 2018 , p. 1103-1125</subfield>
</datafield>
</record>
</collection>